You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/asset_pricing_lph.md
+66-20
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -23,9 +23,10 @@ kernelspec:
23
23
24
24
## Overview
25
25
26
-
This lecture is about foundations of asset-pricing theories that are based on the equation
27
-
$ E m R = 1$, where $R$ is the gross return on an asset, $m$ is a stochastic discount factor, and $E$ is a mathematical
28
-
expectation with respect to the joint distribution of $R$ and $m$.
26
+
This lecture is about some implications of asset-pricing theories that are based on the equation
27
+
$ E m R = 1$, where $R$ is the gross return on an asset, $m$ is a stochastic discount factor, and $E$ is a mathematical expectation with respect to the joint distribution of $R$ and $m$.
28
+
29
+
Instances of this equation occur in many models.
29
30
30
31
```{note}
31
32
Chapter 1 of {cite}`Ljungqvist2012` describes the role that this equation plays in a diverse set of
@@ -35,11 +36,11 @@ models in macroeconomics, monetary economics, and public finance.
35
36
36
37
We aim to convey insights about empirical implications of this equation brought out in the work of Lars Peter Hansen {cite}`HansenRichard1987` and Lars Peter Hansen and Ravi Jagannathan {cite}`Hansen_Jagannathan_1991`.
37
38
38
-
By following their footsteps, from a single equation that prevails in wide class of models, we'll derive
39
+
By following their footsteps, from that single equation we'll derive
39
40
40
41
* a mean-variance frontier
41
42
42
-
* a single-factor model of excess asset returns
43
+
* a single-factor model of excess returns
43
44
44
45
45
46
To do this, we use two ideas:
@@ -51,7 +52,7 @@ To do this, we use two ideas:
51
52
In particular, we'll apply a Cauchy-Schwartz inequality to a population linear least squares regression equation that is
52
53
implied by $E m R =1$.
53
54
54
-
We'll describe how practitioners have implemented the model using
55
+
We'll also describe how practitioners have implemented the model using
55
56
56
57
* cross sections of returns on many assets
57
58
* time series of returns on various assets
@@ -348,37 +349,82 @@ $$
348
349
\end{array}\right.
349
350
$$
350
351
351
-
The image below illustrates a mean-variance frontier.
352
+
Now let's use matplotlib to draw a mean variance frontier.
353
+
354
+
In drawing a frontier, we'll set $\sigma(m) = .25$ and $E m = .99$, values roughly consistent with what many studies calibrate from quarterly US data.
This is a measure of the part of the risk in $R^j$ that is not priced because it can be diversified away,
381
-
being uncorrelated with the stochastic discount factor.
426
+
This is a measure of the part of the risk in $R^j$ that is not priced because it is uncorrelated with the stochastic discount factor and so can be diversified away (i.e., averaged out to zero by holding a diversified portfolio).
0 commit comments